Nakasendo Way

A journey to the heart of Japan

Brought to you by Walk Japan

  • The Journey
    • Map
    • Introduction
    • 1. Kyoto to Sekigahara
    • 2. Sekigahara to Nakatsugawa
    • 3. Nakatsugawa to Kiso-Fukushima
    • 4. Kiso-Fukushima to Nagakubo
    • 5. Nagakubo to Karuizawa
    • 6. Karuizawa to Fukiage
    • 7. Fukiage to Tokyo
    • Post-towns
  • Post Towns
    • About Post Towns
    • Articles
  • History
    • Early History
    • Go-Kaido
    • Politics in the 19th Century: Shogun vs Emperor
    • View all
  • Culture
    • Basho and Poetry
    • Forestry
    • Hot Springs and Shrines
    • Religions
    • View all
  • People
    • Basho’s Life and Work
    • Hiroshige
    • View all
  • Themes
    • Battle of Sekigahara
    • Forestry
    • Pilgrimage
    • Rural Problems
    • Explore topics
    • View all
  • Popular
    • Tokugawa Political System
    • The Highway
    • The Story of the Battle of Sekigahara
    • Omote-ura – Public and Private Faces
    • The Kisoji Post-towns
    • View glossary
  • Galleries
    • City life
    • History
    • Post-Towns
    • View all
  • About
    • About this site
    • About Walk Japan
    • Explore topics
Home / Themes / Economy / The Japanese Economy

The Japanese Economy

Edo Period

The Edo period economy has been hotly debated for years and views of it have radically changed. When the political system was perceived as an unchanging, authoritarian, conservative feudal one throughout the 18th and 19th centuries, the economy was supposed to be very much the same. That is to say, it was  stifled by the oppressive political system. Failing to grow for a hundred and fifty years,  the urban economy became profligate and the rural economy impoverished. Governments could  not achieve balanced budgets leading to fiscal disaster whenever natural disaster struck.  Worse yet, the governments of the shogun and daimyo habitually forced merchants to ‘loan’ money to them, but never paid it back thereby  hindering the growth of the merchant class. For peasants,  there was nothing but grinding poverty, hard work in the rice fields, and a short life  span.

The first half of the Edo period had been quite different. Just like  the government system which grew to perfection, the economy also grew and changed. The  benefits of peace and the growth of urban centers around castle towns stimulated economic  growth, especially in the larger cities like Edo,  Kyoto and Osaka. Stories of immense wealth being  accumulated abound until the Genroku era (1688-1703). At this point, the pace of both  political and economic change slowed. The samurai class, it was argued, sought to preserve  the political status quo by suppressing any further growth in the economy. The merchant  class and commoners dwelling in the cities were increasingly drawn toward ornate  lifestyles which dissipated wealth and energy. Kabuki plays attracted commoners to the  entertainment quarters where tea, poetry, wine, and women soaked up capital  which should have been invested wisely.

With this view of the Edo period economy, the ability of the Meiji period leaders to build up a modern state with a vibrant economy  which could sustain a military machine capable of fighting and beating imperial Russia in  1905 was the first Japanese economic miracle. In fact, economists began to question where  the capital for this miracle came from if both government and economy were as impoverished  as thought; the number and amount of foreign loans in the period were negligible. New  studies of the Edo period were undertaken and they began to show that although slow growth  may have been the rule in the large urban centers, in the smaller cities and in many rural  districts the economy continued to change and grow throughout the Edo period. Along the  Nakasendo, for example, the Omi merchants stimulated commercial agriculture and rural industry. By the end of the Edo period, supposedly impoverished  post-towns like Magome in the Kiso  valley supported families that were quite well off: the Meiji period novelist  Shimazaki Toson’s father was rich enough to travel all the way to Edo and Yokohama more to  see what was happening with the foreign merchants than to transact any business. According  to the new interpretations of the Edo economy, it was this kind of growth which formed a  firm foundation for the development of the Meiji period.

1868-1945

The Meiji period saw the new government pour its  resources almost exclusively into things modern, including the economy. Initially, the  government invested in businesses, but many of them failed to prosper and by 1881 most  were sold at a loss to businessmen. Once these early losses were written off, however, the  remaining businesses, no longer burdened by debt, eventually became profitable. The main  role of the government was to promote modern business and industry by establishing legal  frameworks (like the limited liability stock company) which protected modern economic  growth. The government also helped by establishing standards, especially for export  industries, and a banking system which channeled money into industry. Throughout the  period, the new industries of the modern period and the old, traditional industries complemented and benefited each other.

old textile factories

old textile factories

 

At the end of the 19th century, the government began a series of policies which slowly  introduced shifts into the economy. The most successful industries had been  labor-intensive, low-technology and low-capital ones like textiles.  These were very successful, especially as exporters, earning valuable foreign exchange  which was needed to pay for capital goods which Japan could not produce. The government’s  new policies were designed to force the growth of heavier industries which would demand  more capital and technology and a work force with better skills. The risks were great, but  the value added on and the profits might also be high.

2-1-3

Some of the new government policies included subsidies and protection for high-risk  industries. Ship-building was subsidized beginning in the 1890s, for example. The  intention was to build up a larger transport industry, taking business away from foreign  companies, while encouraging the machine industry and the iron and steel industries which  supplied the ship builders. Concurrently, the government built an integrated iron and  steel foundry to move Japan toward independence in this area.

These policies met with mixed success until World War I in which Japan fought on the  side of the Allies. Suddenly, foreign countries were willing to purchase nearly anything  Japanese industry could produce. In addition, they had difficulty filling Japanese orders  for capital goods. In both cases, Japanese industries found themselves faced with  inexhaustible demand abroad and at home. Prices rose with demand and a level of prosperity  previously undreamed of developed. The average dividend on stocks rose as high as 35% for  the half year during the war. By the end of the war, all the risky investments of the late  Meiji period were made good several times over.

The next fifteen years were not very good for the economy as a whole. The  well-financed, high-technology industries which had been gathering strength continued to  do so. Their sector of the economy generally grew at a rate of around 5% throughout the  period. The traditional industries, such as those which made cloth for Japanese-style  clothing, experienced difficulty. More and more people were turning to Western clothes and  the cloth for Western clothes could not be made by the traditional industries. Competition  between the modern and traditional manufacturing sectors set in and the modern sector had  the better of the contest. The agricultural sector performed  the poorest. Technology and productivity did not change very much and rice imports from  Taiwan and Korea undermined prices. Throughout the period, the government continued its  basic policy of encouraging and promoting growth in the modern sector of the economy,  especially in heavy industry.

2-16-2

Although there was rapid growth in the modern sector, the number of people employed did  not rise as quickly. The majority of the people were employed in agriculture and most of  the remainder were in the traditional sector. Their incomes changed very slowly, creating  a great deal of discontent. When the Great Depression struck in the early 1930s, the  Japanese economy went into a sharper depression than the other industrial economies  experienced. Stories of suffering, starvation, and of farmers selling their daughters into  prostitution abound.

Unlike the rest of the industrialized countries, Japan came out of the depression very  quickly. During the decade of the 1930s, private and public investment in industry,  especially heavy industry continued and accelerated. More and more of the production began  to be demanded by the military which was concerned about future wars and was coming to  dominate government. The takeover of Manchuria in 1931, outbreak of war with China in 1937  and large-scale border clashes with the USSR lent credence to the military’s concern with  increased heavy industrial production which could support the armament industry. By the  end of the decade, growth rates of 8-10% were seen, but not in agriculture which continued  to provide employment for half the population.

The war years, 1937 to 1945, saw the drive toward heavy industrial investment and  development pushed to the extreme. Much of it was probably not wise: for example,  industrial capacity was not increased in the late 1930s as much as the ferocity and length  of war from 1941-1945 was to demand. Of course, in the end, it was all quickly destroyed  in 1944 and 1945 when American bombers attacked.

After 1945

If the economy was devastated by war and defeat, the economic policies of the Allied Occupation were little help. The initial course  was to strip the economy of the capacity to support a war machine. Factories and machinery  were stripped out and shipped abroad as war reparations. The Japanese government pressed  for policies which would revive the industrial economy without success until the  Occupation began to modify the economic policies in 1948 in response to the rise of the  Cold War internationally and resistance in America to subsidizing Japan’s economic  existence (some $1.5 billion was pumped into Japan in the fist years of the Occupation,  yet the entire gross national product was only $1.3 billion in 1946). Finally, steps were  taken to rationalize and stimulate the economy and by 1954 the GNP finally reached the  level it had been twenty years earlier.

The Occupation had taken other steps to improve the economy. It had broken up some of  the largest corporations (Mitsui, Mitsubishi, Sumitomo and Yasuda in particular) in order  to increase competition and ‘democratize’ the economy. It had also redistributed farm land  so that tenant farmers gained ownership of the land and with it an intense interest in  improving agriculture. Later on, subsidies in the form of guaranteed prices for rice  brought long term stability and growth to the rural sector.

Throughout the second part of the Occupation period and after, the Japanese government  pursued policies similar to those of the prewar period: stimulate and protect heavy  industry as the leading sector of the economy. The benefits of growth here would  eventually spread into the service sector, traditional manufacturing and agriculture.

A combination of guided investment, encouragement of export industries, careful quality  control, productivity increases, protection, and technology imports yielded results which  came to be called the Japanese economic miracle in the 1950s and 1960s with annual growth  rates consistently above 10%. By the mid-1960s, Japan began to join the major  international economic organizations such as General Agreement on Trade and Tarries (GATT)  and the International Monetary Fund (IMF). To do so, the many barriers and tariffs which  had protected the economy began to be dismantled, a process which continued over the next  decades.

The process of opening up the economy has not been smooth and it has received much  criticism, especially in recent years when Japanese trade surpluses with the industrial  world have been large. Much of the criticism focuses on non-official barriers such as an  archaic and complex distribution which inhibits penetration or a tradition of loyalty  between companies which makes it difficult for a new company, especially a foreign one, to  make a sale. These may all be gradually changing, but the process is very slow and  frustrating to the many foreign businessmen in Japan and their governments.

Recent developments

A number of recent developments are interesting to note. One is that with the growth of  Japan as an international economy more and more Japanese businessmen and their families  are being posted abroad. They bring back to Japan perceptions, interests, experiences and  abilities which are new and different, yet increasingly common as their numbers increase.  One must wonder what sort of impact this kind of intimate contact with the outside will  have in the future.

Another is the relationship between urban and rural Japan. In terms of income, there is  little difference; if anything, rural families have had slightly higher incomes for some  time because most households combine farming with non-agricultural work. Yet everyone  perceives the cities to be where the opportunities are greatest and the quality of life  higher. Rural depopulation is a continuing problem which has not been solved. In addition  to centrally generated programs, the government has even presented each rural village with  a substantial amount of money (about US$800,000) and left it to the village to use the  money to try to stem the decay. Aside from rice, most of what Japan consumes is imported  from abroad. What then is the future role of agriculture?

As the economy has become prosperous, the type of work which Japanese want to do has  changed too. The young middle or high school graduates who gushed out of rural districts  in the 1950s and took jobs in construction are now parents of children with university  degrees. They would not think of taking on such work. Labor intensive industries must  either move abroad, especially to Asian nations with lower labor costs, or bring in  foreign workers to do the jobs. The one solution causes economic growth abroad and  structural change at home; the other introduces social problems which few are willing to  confront.

shortage of habitable living space

shortage of habitable living space

The concentration of industry and population in urban  areas has caused increases in land prices which, in the 1980s, were stupendous. Young  people found prices too high to dream of home purchase while those who inherited their  parents’ home found the tax bill so high that the inheritance had to be sold.

In 1991 to 1993, real estate prices fell from exorbitant levels to merely immoderate  levels. At the same time, the stock market fell nearly 60%. These two falls wiped out  immense amounts of paper assets and, with the recession of 1992 and early 1993, raised  questions about the possibility of an economic ‘melt down’, a downward spiraling recession  as people reacted by not spending, forcing losses on even the largest companies for the  first time in decades. The stock market has strengthened and to a certain extent  recovered, suggesting that the worst fears were never more than that, but the experience  has underlined a long-standing feeling among many Japanese that their economy is a fragile  one.

Added to these difficulties is the steadily rising value of the yen which stayed at 360  to the US dollar for decades, but rose to less than 110 to the dollar in the middle of  1993 with expectations of further strengthening. Each increase in the yen’s value has put  pressure on the profits of export industries. At some point, Japanese exports could be  priced out of foreign markets, casting further doubt on the economic  health of the nation.

2-42-3

Category: Economy, Themes

Tweet
  • Facebook
  • Twitter

From the glossary

  • Shogun

    Shogun (full title, “Seii Taishogun” or ‘Barbarian Subduing Generalissimo’) was the title of the hegemon of Japan during the feudal periods (1185-1868). The shogun was theoretically subordinate to the emperor. Although nominally he was the supreme authority, his power over local affairs was limited by the rights of the feudal barons, the daimyo.

Nakasendo Way is brought to you by Walk Japan Ltd., which operates the original tours to the Nakasendo Way.

Walk Japan

Company Profile

Walk Japan Ltd.
1736 Radio City,
505 Hennessy Road,
Causeway Bay,
Hong Kong SAR

Report errors and updates


© Copyright 2021 Walk Japan

Site Map

  • Home
  • The Journey
  • History
  • Culture
  • People
  • Galleries
  • Glossary

Connect with us

  • Facebook
  • Instagram
  • Twitter

Explore

administration barrier station post-town religion scandal shinto train transport travel volcano